Archives
June 12, 1979
Economic Value of Public Education
Schooling is the largest US industry!
By Howard
Hobbs, Ph.D.
LOS ANGELES -- Education is the largest single industry in
the United States. It is highly suhsidized by the government. Estimating
the economic value of an education required the application of benefit-cost
techniques to transform so-called intangiblebenefits into policy
parameters.
It is, therefore, highly appropriate to
devote in this study considerable space for the treatment of public-expenditure
analysis in education.
The general case for government intervention
in the economy appears to be relatively important. Although education
is not a pure public good, it is generally regarded as a quasi-public
good.
For example, a lecture that is given to
five students may be given, without substantial loss to one hundred
students, provided that a large enough lecture hall is available.
Some loss to the five original students
may be sustained due to the reduced personal contact with the lectul
c but it is clear that some element of joint consumption exists.
Of course, excludability is possible. And for that reason an educational
system could and does operate through the free market system.
Perhaps the most important reason for government's
involvement in education is the alleged existence of external effects.
It is commonly felt that, for example, elementary education for
Mr. Jones' children is not entirely Mr. Jones' business.
If Mr. Jones fails to provide such education
to his children, society as a whole may suffer. This may be reflected
in the fear that an uneducated child may be so unproductive that
he is likely to become a public charge.
Further, it many parents, like Mr. Jones,
fail to provide "adequate" education to their children, society
will suffer in the form of a less educated electorate - considered
to be less able to make "rational" electoral selections - reduced
demwid for and usefulness of such items as checking accounts, books
and magazines, alld so on.
Moreover, education is expected to affect
one's associates, employers, acid 83 children; studies have documented
that the more educated parents are likely to provide more education
to their children (what is termed the intergenerational effect).
So, the belief that external effects of
education are quite important is probably the single most important
reason for government involvement in education. Other reasons, such
as risk and time preference, are also relevant.
Even more important is the desire to effect
income redistribution through educational expenditures. It has long
been asserted that government subsidization of education permits
a greater degree of equality of educational opportunity, which,
in turn, leads to greater equality of income and wealth.
Whether each or both parts of this assertion
are true is subject to at least some controversy.' Despite the lack
of consensus in this regard, it appears that public funds have frequently
been channeled into education on the basis of income distribution
goals rather than allocative ones.
Of paramount importance to a rational analysis
of public investment in education is the ability to provide comprehensive
measures of costs and benefits.
Clearly, the measurement of educational
benefits is far from simple. Furthermore, measurement of educational
costs is not quite as simple as one might expect. The reason for
this is that direct costs (operating costs, interest on debt, and
capital costs) are only a part of total costs.
An important cost element that must be
estimated is earnings foregone, i.e., the opportunity cost of employment
to persons who choose to engage in an educational endeavor.
Educational costs may be thought of in
three ways, separate direct and indirect costs. As a general principle,
all economic costs are opportunity costs, i.e., the opportunities
foregone because an educational investment is undertaken. The direct
costs are more readily measurable because educational institutions
systematically provide expenditure data. Indirect costs must be
imputed.
In addition, educational cost data usually
reflect the total cost, or average cost, of educational services
provided over a wide range of educational programs.
For policy purposes it is frequently necessary
to estimate marginal costs associated with a given program or range
of programs. In what follows we will give consideration to both
the general scheme by which cost categories might be estimated and
the analytical framework that might be utilized to estimate average
and/or marginal costs.
Estimates of direct costs of education
have been obtained for a wide range of educational activities over
the present century. Various studies endeavored to measure the costs
of specific educational programs (such as costs of compensatory
education, dropout programs, vocational programs, etc.).
The data base for most of the studies has
been expenditures on school operations, debt service, and capital
outlay. The expenditure data provided by school reports are highly
useful for some purposes and only marginally useful for others.
For example, if it is desired to obtain
estimates of aggregate resources entering elementary and secondary
public education, data reported by the U.S. Office of Education
or the National Education Association are highly useful, even if
not complete.'
On the other hand, if one wishes to consider
the costs of specific programs within the general framework of public
elementary and secondary schools, the availability of desired data
is often limited. One problem with expenditure data is that they
are not necessarily identical to costs.
If a set of expenditure data is based on
an academic year whereas comparable benefit data are available only
for a fiscal or calendar year, some adjustment in the data must
be made. Further, if expenditure data are based on methods other
than accrual, some difference between expenditure and costs is likely
to exist.
Capital outlays are not generally identical
to capital costs. Capital costs should be estimated on the basis
of capital consumption (depreciation) and implicit rent, while capital
outlays and interest reflect payment for new and old structures,
respectively.
The need to obtain separate estimates of capital
costs has recently been recognized by several economists. A more
fundamental problem with expenditure data is that they do not necessarily
reflect the absolute minimum costs necessary to sustain a given
educational activity.
The fact that Edison High School
spends $2.5 million on its secondary education curricula cannot
be taken to imply that the same educational services could not be
obtained for less than that sum.
Studies have shown that schools that are
too small (and perhaps too large) are likely to spend more per pupil
for the same educational output (variously measured by achievement
scores and/or an index of "key" educational in puts).4
Since economic cost implies the absolute
minimum cost necessary to sustain a given activity, utilization
of school expenditure data is likely to overestimate the true potential
social costs.
Indirect cost expenditure data, even if
the above mentioned difficulties are assumed away, do not provide
a sufficiently broad basis for determining educational costs.
The most important omission is earnings
foregone. It should be noted at the outset that the relevance of
earnings foregone has been a source of controversy in recent years.
Yet most authors - this author included - hold the view that foregone
earnings should be considered explicitly.
The rationale for this is quite
simple: suppose a given group of individuals who are presently in
Edison would have decided against going to school. Presumably, they
would have been engaged in some activity, most likely they would
have gone to work.
The earnings that they could have earned
if they did not go to school should be considered an integral part
of the cost of going to school. The argument that some schooling
is in any event compulsory or that child labor laws restrict the
work activities of young persons does not really hold water.
Here is why. These individuals would still
have been capable of performing some or any productive activities.
Therefore, estimates should be made to provide as accurate an estimate
of earnings foregone as is practicable.
Another objection to earnings foregone
has been the argument that when educational costs of a large number
of students are considered - as distinct from a consideration of
a few students only - the measurement of earnings foregone is impossible
since an injection of a large number of individuals into the labor
force would likely upset wages and the occupational structure of
the labor force.
That such an "aggregation problem" is likely
to exist cannot be dismissed. The dilemma facing the decision maker
is whether he should ignore earnings foregone altogether, or provide
estimates based on current labor market conditions. It seems to
this author that ignoring earnings foregone is clearly indefensible.
In the absence of a method by which the
aggregation problem could be solved, it is convenient to assume
that the existence of an aggregation problem would not materially
affect estimates of earnings foregone. Capital Costs.
Since capital outlays and interest cannot
be used as measures of capital costs (in any given year), and since
depreciation must also be imputed, one might consider the estimation
of capital costs under the "indirect cost" category.
To estimate depreciation of buildings and
equipment one should obtain, ideally, a schedule of actual wear
and tear as well as obsolescence of the assets. Such schedules can
rarely be obtained, however.
Consequently, some other methods must be
used. The simplest procedure would be to use one of the acceptable
depreciation methods used by accountants ( allowed by the Internal
Revenue Service), such as the straight-line depreciation schedule
which is merely a function of expected life of the asset and its
salvage value.'
If a given 'Depreciation in a given year
= (original cost of asset less salvage value) =(number of years
of economic life of asset). If an asset was purchased at a sum of
$X, has an expected economic life of n years, and has an expected
salvage value of $S, the straight-line method would imply an annual
depreciation of $(X - S)/n.
There are other methods.
One could obtain the market value of assets
and compute depreciation for each class of assets on the basis of
past experience. Market value may be estimated on the basis of insurance
valuations (unless undepreciated original cost is the basis for
insurance) or independent appraisals.
One other method that has been used in
several studies is the capital recovery factor (CRF), which provides
for annual ammortization of original cost and interest payments.'
In addition to the depreciation estimates,
one should consider the rental value of school properties. If the
buildings and equipment were rented to private schools or to other
enterprises, some rental value would be forthcoming.
Clearly, there is no uniform rental value
on school properties. In areas where such facilities do not have
alternative uses, at least in the short run, rental values would
be negligible. In other, more populated areas, rental values may
be rather large.
Cost of Tax Exemption. Several other types
of costs must be considered. One of these is the cost of tax exemption.
The fact that educational institutions are exempted from payments
of various federal, state, and local taxes, reduces the prices at
which schools are able to buy goods and services.
If market prices are the correct guide
for efficient resource allocation, the lower effective prices paid
by schools should be adjusted to reflect going market prices. Here,
again, there is an element of aggregation involved, since property
taxes, for instance, in a given locality are by-andlarge levied
for the purpose of running the schools.
Had the schools been eliminated, most of
the property tax would be superfluous. It follows that a full adjustment
for lower effective prices is not required.
What portion of tax advantage should be
considered as reflecting effective lower prices depends on the extent
to which the cost of educational services determines the tax rate.
Also, it is necessary to obtain the assessed valuation of tax-exempt
properties.
Other Costs. Finally, transportation costs,
costs of supplies and books, and other costs sustained by parents
and children (not accounted for in operating expenditures) must
be estimated and included in the calculations. Lack of data has
forced researchers to employ arbitrary rules of thumb to estimate
such costs.
Ideally, data should be gathered from students,
their families, or sellers of school supplies, for the approximate
costs of such activities.
The benefits of education are atone and
the same time obvious but difficult to measure. It is common knowledge
that education is a means by which persons could climb up both the
social and economic ladders in society.
But the exact magnitudes of such benefits
are extremely difficult to estimate. Still, consider able progress
has been made in recent years in this area.
For descriptive purposes, it would be useful
to distinguish between direct and indirect benefits and between
consumption and investment benefits. Direct `' benefits are those
that may be directly attributable to a given educational endeavor.
Several classes of indirect benefits will also
be discussed. In addition, estimation of benefits has largely been
confined to what has been termed the investment component, as distinct
from the consumption element. The investment component includes
the benefits of education that are manifested in increased productivity
of individuals.
Consumption benefits are largely confined
to the satisfaction people get while undertaking an educational
endeavor; it should be noted, however, that insofar as education
increases one's capacity to enjoy literature, art, etc., consumption
benefits extend to future periods (following completion of the educational
program) as well. Direct Benefits.
Most econoicsts who have attempted to tackle
the job of measuring educational benefits have employed the "human
capital" approach. This approach is based on the presumption that
educational investment is much like other investments which individuals
could undertake - an investment which has an expected return over
cost - the only difference being that education is an investment
in persons, not physical assets.
The most common procedure to measure such
returns has been the additional lifetime earnings method. This method
is used to calculate the extra income an individual is likely to
earn over a lifetime as a consequence of a given educational investment.
Consider additional lifetime earnings and
benefits to an individual with 8 years of schooling of completing
high school (12 years of schooling). Census data cross-classified
by age and education have been available for three consecutive decades
(1950, 1960, and 1970).
Take the 1970 Census, for example, and
calculate mean incomes for all individuals who completed 12 years
of schooling for each age. Do the same for lifetime incomes of individuals
who completed only 8 years of schooling.
Then calculate, for each age, the difference
between mean income at age x with 12 years of schooling and mean
income at this age with only 8 years. When these differences are
summed over one's expected productive lifetime, say up to age 65,
we obtain the extra lifetime income due to secondary education.
Symbolically, let mean income at age x
for an individual with schooling level s be denoted by YXs. Mean
income at age x for persons undertakings - 1 Table 7-3 Benefits
of Higher Horizons Progam Elementary School Junior High School 1.
Discounted additional lifetime income associated
with one extra year of schooling $2,410 $2,838 2. Average percent
of equivalent year of schooling gained due to the program 3% 3.3%
3. Benefits per student (line 1 X line 2) $ 72 $ 94 Source: Adapted
from Ribich (1968), Table 5, p. 71. ferentials, and then the simpler
method (outlined above) could be employed to calculate the adjusted
lifetime income streams.
Value of Incremental Achievement. An interesting
method for studying the potential of special programs for increasing
the achievement of "disadvantaged" students (known generally as
compensatory education programs) was suggested by Ribich. This method
assumes that the major educational output is achievement in basic
skills.
Ideally, a production function approach
should be used to estimate the extra achievement in basic skills
due to a given extra educational effort.'9
Since achievement scores are given in terms
of equivalent years of education, the method permits an evaluation
of how many equivalent years of education (or fraction thereof)
the average student acquired as a result of a specific program.
The additional educational output is then
transformed into additional lifetime earnings, utilizing the cross-sectional
additional lifetime-income approach.
This method is illustrated in Table 7-3
for the Higher Horizons program in New York City. These benefits
are based on 1959 data, on the assumption that a discount rate of
5 percent is appropriate. When the Ribich method is
properly utilized, it has far-reaching implications.
However, Ribich himself did not consider
explicitly an educational production function in determining educational
benefits. The education production function would isolate the benefits
of a given program when other factors are considered simultaneously.
In general, let output (achievement scores
in the Ribich case) be denoted by Y. Consider, further, a vector
of n schooling-related factors, X1 , X2, . . . , Xn, and 18Ribich
(1968), Chapters IV-V. 19 The educational production function is
described below.
Similar frameworks have been employed by
Hunt and Rogers to study the returns to college education, Cross-Sectional
and Cohort Methods.
Another difficulty with the additional-lifetime-income
approach as discussed here is the use of cross-section data. That
is, income expected at age x was based upon mean income of those
who were x years old at the time the census was taken.
Consequently, the method assumes no change
in the earnings structure as well as no increase in earnings differentials
due to economic growth. (If economic growth were to increase all
wages in the economy by the same absolute amount, no change in earnings
differentials would be expected; however, if economic growth increase
all wages by the same percent, income differentials would increase.)
There are two alternatives that may be
employed to account for economic growth. The simplest approach,
used by Becker, Klinov-Malul, and Danielsen, is to assume that earnings
differentials are likely to increase at, say, one or two percent,
and then recalculate expected earnings differentials accordingly.
In Becker's calculations, an adjustment
in earnings differentials for an assumed growth rate of 2 percent
is shown to increase the internal rate of return to college education
by over two percentage points. The other, more complex alternative,
is to employ the so-called cohort method." In principle, the idea
is simple.
One needs to follow the earnings experience
of a given cohort over a period of time and then use such age-earning
information to project current expected income of individuals in
a given educational level.
For example, we may observe the earnings
of secondary school graduates, all of whom were 18 in 1925, from
1921 to 1972 (when they reache the assumed retirement age of 65).
The stream of,earnings over that period would reflect changes in
the structure of the labor market as well as economic growth. If
the same procedure were employed to measure earnings of another
cohort, who were 18 in 1925 but who completed only 8 years of schooling,
it would be possible to study the earnings differentials due to
secondary schooling (with adjustment made to control for nonschooling
effects).
Although the cohort method should work
rather well in studying educational returns in retrospect, it is
doubtful that the method is very useful for predicting future earnings.
For it would be necessary to employ data
dating bac as many as 50 years if we are to get a complete earnings
stream based on the cohort method. Nevertheless, it has been shown
by Miller that the cohort method can be used to suggest the expected
effect of economic growth on earning difference. [Hunt (1963) and
Rogers (1969].
Another method for studying the potential
of special programs for increasing the achievement of "disadvantaged"
students (known generally as compensatory education programs) assumes
that the major educational output is achievement in basic skills.
Ideally, a production-function approach
should be used to estimate the extra achievement in basic skills
due to a given extra educational effort.
Since achievement scores are given in terms
of equivalent years of education, the method permits an evaluation
of how many equivalent years of education the average student acquired
as a result of a specific program.
The additional educational output is then
transformed into additional lifetime earnings, utilizing the cross-sectional
additionallifetime-income approach. This method is based on the
assumption that a discount rate of 5 percent is appropriate.
When the method is properly utilized, it
has far-reaching implications. However, the education production
function isolates the benefits of a given program when other factors
are considered simultaneously.
In general, the meaning of the equation
derived is, simply, that schooling and nonschooling factors simultaneously
determine the level of output. Among the schooling factors we may
consider such variables as teacher attributes, building and equipment
resources, library books, administrative and clerical help, and
so on.
Among nonschooling attributes one might
include socioeconomic conditions, intelligence, student motivation,
race, sex, and other "environmental" factors.
In the compensatory education case discussed
above, we would add another variable to distinguish between those
who did and those who did not enroll in the particular program.
If that variable had the form: 1 = participated in program, 0 =
otherwise, the coefficient of this variable (determined through
the employment of a regression equation) would indicate the extra
output Y associated with enrollment in the program, other things
remaining equal.
Although the production-function approach
is theoretically valid, its empirical counterpart has so far been
generally far less than staisfactory. One problem is that we do
not as yet have a firm learning theory that would enable us to hypothesize
a priori the shape of the production function given by equation
(7.8).
For example, we do not know whether it
should be linear or nonlinear (and if so of what exact form) with
respect to each of the variables. So, the analysis is limited to
one output only - even if it is such an important factor as achievement
in basic skills - we are bound to distort the facts since it is
obvious that the educational system does more than just train people
to read, write, and do some arithmetic.
What is clearly needed is a model with
a system of equations, each of which pertains to a single output,
to be solved by means of one of the simultaneous-equation methods.
In addition to the direct benefits (in
form of expected increased lifetime earnings), it has long been
asserted that educational investments bring forth benefits to society
that go beyond the mere increase in productivity. Consumption benefits
have already been mentioned.
Education may increase one's enjoyment of
his job (or, alternatively, reduce his disutility of work), change
one's attitudes and habits, and increase one's geographic and occupational
mobility.
Education enables individuals to perform
various activities outside the market whose value is not commonly
measured. An example is the filing of income tax returns.
Other obvious "nonmarket" benefits are
such common activities as driving and typewriting. Another type
of benefit is the intergeneration effect, mentioned earlier. The
additional education of one generation is likely to result in their
offsprings receiving so much extra education that part or all of
the older generation's educational investment is paid back in the
form of intergenerational benefit. This suggests that educational
investment not only increases the productivity of those undertaking
the investment, but also enhances the probability that future generations
will invest in educational endeavors that will increase society's
productivity in the future.
To all of these we may add another important
item - external benefits. These are the benefits that an individual
cannot himself capture but which are diffused into society. These
include inventions and innovations for which the inventors or innovators
cannot hope to be fully compensated. In many cases, indeed, an invention
is recognized long after the inventor has already passed on.
Other types of external benefits (for example, reduced juvenile
crime) have not been measured. Considerable effort must be directed
towards these issues before estimates may be used for policy purposes.
Benefit-Cost Analysis To determine the social worth of a given educational
program at Edison High School in Fresno, California, the benefits
must be balanced against the costs.
Since there is disagreement among educational
economists on which benefit-cost framework is best (for a given
decision problem), the literature supports broaderning the reasearch
database to include studies in which the net-present-value criterion
is employed, others in which the benefit/cost ratio rule was employed,
others (perhaps the majority) in which the primary decision tool
has been the internalrate-of return rule. Since the policy decision
is sensitive to the choice of a decision rule, it would have been
desirable if results were given in a manner flexible enough that
each of the three rules can be utilized, if so desired.
The manner by which the net-present-value
rule may be deployed uses data produced by Hansen that discounted
additional lifetime earnings for persons completing 12 years of
schooling in comparison to only 8 years. From these discounted sums
we deduct the present value of direct costs of schooling, estimated
to be about $385 per student per year in 1949-1950. The difference
is the net present value of secondary school education, based on
1949 data, for several rates of discount.
Clearly, the data show that high school
education was a worthwhile social investment in 1949. The data in
Part II of Table 5-1 were derived in a similar manner - with annual
direct college costs in 1949-1950 estimated by Hansen at 5943 per
student per year.
The results in the table suggest that positive
net present values are obtained only when the rate of discount applied
is somewhat less than 10 percent.
Clearly, these results are based on a model
in which virtually all of the costs were considered (earnings foregone
are automatically deducted from the earnings stream) whereas only
the direct (and measurable) benefits have been accounted for explicitly.
The quantity and quality of research on
the economic value of education has increased considerably in recent
years. Yet, the study of the economic benefits to graduate education
has lagged behind. Census data concerning earnings classified by
age and educational attainment are now available but, only on individuals
with at least some graduate work - and not for individuals with
M.A. or Ph.D. degrees (or their equivalents).
There are several puzzling issues related
to the returns to graduate education.
First: How, and to what extent, do (a)
the private, and (b) the social returns to graduate education (measured
by incremental current and/or lifetime income) vary by: number of
years of study in a given degree program degree(s)earned field of
study occupation ability and achievement quality of the institution
or department granting the highest degree financial support while
in school socioeconomic background location in one of several regions
in the U.S. type of employer?
Second: To what extent are the answers
to the above question modified when estimates of the value of fringe
benefits and nonpecuniary income are incorporated in the calculation
of net earnings?
Third: Are there significant external benefits
due to graduate education?
The importance of human
capital in assessing the economic viability of a nation dates
back to Adam Smith. Smith realized that the optimal attainment of
efficiency in the division of labor would be impossible without
education. He even dared compare man to a machine, insofar as individual
skills are concerned.
While other early writers recognized the
concept of human capital, few considered human capital to be of
central importance in the formulation of economic models.
Recently published research has largely
emanated from the pioneering works of Walter Becker, who recognized
the need to adjust the gross relationship between education and
earnings for ability difference (a function of superior intelligence
and motivation, rather than schooling).Becker relies on past studies
and then deducts a certain proportion of the earnings differentials
from the gross estimate to reduce his estimates of earnings less
than optimal.
[Editor's
Note: Dr. Howard Hobbs is a Ford Fellow emeritus and is completing
post-doctoral economics reasearch at The University of Southern
California on the Advanced Studies Program at Edison High School
in Fresno, CA.]
Letter to Editor
©1876-2002
by The Fresno Republican Newspaper.
All rights reserved.
|